by SUDHA R. SHENOY
Miss
Shenoy, of India, is pursuing graduate studies in economics at the
School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London.
Within
the past twenty years Hong Kong has grown from a minor trading port
into a center of manufacturing, with exports to some seventy nations
round the world. Hong Kong seems to have found a formula for development
that is not widely understood.
The
number of industrial establishments in Hong Kong rose from 947 in 1947
to 9,301 in 1967, the number of employees during that same period
rising from 51,627 to 431,973.¹ Exports of manufactured goods in 1965 were 41/2
times the 1953 level. By all such tests of growth, Hong Kong compares
most favorably with the United Nations’ target rate of 3.5 to 5 per cent
a year. It may be added that Hong Kong has never experienced the
chronic shortage of exchange earnings supposed to typify
underdeveloped countries.
Cotton
manufactures have remained the staple among export items, accounting
for as much as two-thirds of the total in earlier years, but down now to
about 55 per cent. Initially, simple knitted goods, piece goods, and
yarn formed the major part of these exports, but the industry has
rapidly diversified to the manufacture of a large variety of clothing
and the more highly finished textiles. Recent exports include woolen
knitwear, brocades, carpets, and lace. Textile machinery, originally
manufactured just for local use, is now being produced for export as
well.
Such
items as firecrackers, Chinese foodstuffs, and bamboo manufactures
once formed a major part of the export list. But by 1955, a wide range
of consumer goods were being manufactured, including torches, nylon
gloves, electric clocks, and enamelware. Current exports have moved
further into the industrial range: plastics, cameras, transistor radios,
air conditioners, water-heaters, light machinery (such as pumps and
generators), and precision engineering products (e.g., watch parts and
aircraft components) are now made in Hong Kong.
Hong
Kong’s ship breaking industry is the largest in the world. At first,
the scrap was utilized in the local construction industry; but this,
too, is now being exported. With the development of the shipbuilding
industry, yachts, and trawlers were exported, mainly to the United
States. Tugs, lighters, and barges were built for Borneo, Kuwait, and
Ceylon.
Hong
Kong’s industrial development thus proceeded along classic lines, from
the simpler consumer goods to the more sophisticated varieties; from
light industrial products to the intermediate types. Hong Kong has never
suffered from inability to import heavy industrial goods, which
supposedly hampers the development of many areas.3 Nor is
there a Five- or a Ten-Year Plan or other such centralized resource
allocation in Hong Kong. Indeed, no government "planner" might have
expected Hong Kong to set an example of rapid development. It has few,
if any, of the textbook preconditions for successful development.}
The domestic market for many of its exports is narrow or nonexistent. It
has no natural resources (with the exception of an excellent harbor),
and no coal, oil, or other domestic fuel supply. The tillable area—13
per cent of a total of less than 400 square miles—is of poor quality.
Hong Kong thus has to import virtually all its food, fuel, and raw
materials. Even drinking water is pumped in from China.
No Tools for Planning
The
Colony has other handicaps from a planner’s point of view: it lacks
some of the most elementary government statistics and other guides for
control over the economy. Figures on registered industrial employment
and daily wage-rates began to be collected in 1947. Trade figures were
added the following year. A Retail Price Index was constructed in 1953
and an Index of Wage Rates the following year. But there are still no
official national income estimates, or even an Index of Industrial
Production. There are no official balance-of-payment figures, no
restrictions on trade and payments, no export duties, no central bank;
banking regulation is negligible. Consequently, the government simply
has no basis for applying the various fiscal, monetary, and other
measures recommended in most modern textbooks on public finance and
development.
For most of the past twenty years, the highest income-tax rate was 121/2 per cent (currently 151/2 per
cent); taxes on earnings and real property, and import duties on a
narrow range of commodities (chiefly tobacco, wines, and drugs) are the
main sources of revenue. Up to 1955, primary education (which is not
compulsory), subsidized housing, basic medical services, and other
"welfare" items accounted for slightly more than one-third of total
government expenditure, with an equal proportion being spent on roads,
water supply and other "economic" services. By 1968, "welfare"
expenditures had risen to two-thirds of the total, the total having
increased from an average of HK $271 million in the years1948-55 to HK
$1,800 million in 1968. (U.S. $1.00 = H.K. $6.00.) The increased
provision of such services was made possible by rising productivity.
Hong
Kong has no minimum wage legislation, a negligible amount of labor
legislation, and only a few very weak unions. Yet, take-home pay doubled
between 1958 and 1967. The retail price index rose only 9 per cent in
the interim, so this represented a substantial increase in real
earnings. Living standards rose significantly, as exemplified at a
basic level by changes in diet. Per capita rice consumption fell, while
its quality improved, and more meat and vegetables were consumed.
Imports of frozen meat rose from 26,000 tons in 1955 to 121,000 tons in
1965. Hong Kong thus combined rapid economic growth with a rise in
living standards.
Quotas and Restrictions
Hong
Kong’s development has proceeded entirely without
government-to-government "aid." Indeed, other governments have sought
to curb their imports of goods manufactured in the Colony. The first
quotas were imposed in 1954, by the governments of the U.S.A., Pakistan,
and Thailand. The next year a number of South-East Asian governments
followed suit, but Hong Kong manufacturers switched to markets in Africa
and Latin America. In 1958, the U.K. government imposed limits on
imports of textiles and clothing manufactured in Hong Kong; the U.S.
government began limiting such imports in 1963.
The
story behind these last restrictions is revealing. It begins with the
so-called agricultural price support policy of the U.S. government,
which among other things, maintains the domestic price of U.S. cotton
above the world level. The Department of Agriculture, then finding
itself laden with "excess" supplies of cotton, added an export subsidy
to offset the price support. Meanwhile, imported textiles were
beginning to replace U.S.-made textiles in U.S. markets, as foreign
manufacturers bought cotton (including American cotton) at world—not
U.S.—prices, while their labor costs were well below the American level.
American manufacturers turned to Washington for protection against
losses; and, in 1961, a "countervailing" import duty was imposed—to
offset the export subsidy to offset the price support. Hong Kong
textiles, however, sold so well despite this additional burden that
import quotas were placed in 1963. Hong Kong manufacturers have
responded by improving the quality of their exports.
Other
countries restricting Hong Kong imports by means of heavy duties,
quotas, and the like include Australia, Canada, France, Ghana, New
Zealand, Nigeria, Norway, Rhodesia, Singapore, Switzerland, Tanzania,
Uganda, and the West Indies.
Laissez-Faire
How
did Hong Kong achieve all this? It has been suggested that the
availability of capital and the presence of a large refugee
population—obviously possessed of a certain amount of get-up-and-go are
perhaps the two chief factors contributing to Hong Kong’s success.5
But those individuals who came as refugees to Hong Kong possessed their
enterprising qualities even before they arrived; nor does a waterless
rock off the Chinese coast offer the best prospects for investment. The
difference lay in the economic environment, in the free markets created
by policy: "Almost complete laissez-faireism unleashed human
potentialities, paralysed in other countries by elaborate control
systems." The government made no attempt to impose or preserve any
particular resource allocation, but provided instead the stable legal,
fiscal, and monetary framework that the market requires for optimal
functioning. This use of the pricing system meant the full utilization
of the empirical knowledge of ever-changing circumstances, which can
never be centralized, but is only available scattered among
individuals.? Resource allocations were thus determined, via profit and loss, by international consumer preference.
Hong
Kong’s economic growth was part of this general process. Investment in
directions where returns were rapid and large meant that output and thus
real incomes were raised rapidly; this, in turn, made higher saving and
investment possible—but in continuously more sophisticated types of
machinery, which permitted not only further increases in production but
also diversification of output. Resources were thus created where none
existed before.
One fundamental point must be stressed: the course of Hong Kong’s development could scarcely have been predicted before it
occurred, even on the basis of a detailed knowledge of the past growth
of the now-developed nations. No one, in 1947, had any idea of what a
developed Hong Kong might look like! It was only by the market process that this, in fact, became evident.
This
logic is capable of wider application. In 1750, on the basis of the
knowledge available then, it would hardly have been possible to "plan"
in advance for the development of the North Atlantic region. Both North
American and Western Europe were still relatively underdeveloped, and
no one knew, in concrete terms, what shape any development might take!
This illustrates the contradiction in what is termed "planned economic
development": since we do not know what a developed Africa, Asia, and
Latin America might look like, we are necessarily limited to planning
for the reproduction of what has already been achieved, in the past,
elsewhere! The market process, on the other hand, sets no such
limitations; it is adapted to the realization of hitherto latent and
unknown possibilities. Inasmuch as the underdeveloped nations represent,
as it were, a vast realm of such unrealized potentialities, it is
above all essential in these areas to create the environment for a
market economy.8
No comments:
Post a Comment