By Donald J. Boudreaux
Platitudes are a poor basis for policy. The reason is that, no matter how melodious they sound, platitudes are practically meaningless. People who utter platitudes often seem to be saying something meaningful when in fact they're merely stating the obvious.
A
good way to test if someone is speaking in platitudes is to ask
yourself if you can imagine a normal human adult believing the opposite.
Suppose
someone informs you that he favors policies that promote human
happiness. Can you imagine, say, your neighbor responding, “I disagree. I
favor policies that promote human misery”? Probably not.
If
you cannot imagine any normal person disagreeing with some
proclamation, then that proclamation is a platitude. It tells you
nothing of substance.
Consider today's fashionable
calls for “sustainability.” The academy, media, cyberspace are full of
people proclaiming support for policies that promote economic and
environmental “sustainability.” So whenever you hear such proclamations,
ask if you can envision a sane adult sincerely disagreeing.
You'll
discover, of course, that you can't imagine anyone seriously supporting
“unsustainability.” Therefore, you should conclude that mere
expressions of support for “sustainability” are empty. And they can be
downright harmful if they mislead people into supporting
counterproductive government policies.
Substantive
issues involving sustainability invoke questions that have non-obvious
answers. For example: At what rate must the supply of a resource fall
before we conclude that continued use of that resource is unsustainable?
Fifty percent annually? Ten percent? One percent?
Because
the correct answer to this question depends (among other factors) on
how much humans care about the future — and because there's no good
reason why we humans should care about the world as it might be many
years from now as much as we care about the world as it might be a few
days from now — policies and activities that will eventually result in
the depletion of some resource are not necessarily unsustainable in any
sense that really matters to humans today. If the appropriate human time
horizon is, say, 500 years, then activities that will cause petroleum
supplies to be exhausted in 550 years are “sustainable” within our
relevant time horizon.
Economically sophisticated
readers will respond, “Not so fast! Even if we won't completely run out
of petroleum until well past the time that is relevant for human beings
alive today, falling supplies of petroleum will start to raise the price
of petroleum long before 500 years from now.” This claim is true — but
it's a reason to worry less, not more, about “sustainability.”
A
rising price of petroleum serves as a spur to sustainable practices.
First, the rising price prompts consumers voluntarily to cut back on the
use of petroleum. Second, this rising price creates incentives for
entrepreneurs to find or create petroleum substitutes. And the steeper
the price rise, the stronger are these incentives.
Nearly
every resource commonly used today likely has potential substitutes —
recall that newly discovered petroleum in the 19th century quickly
substituted for wood, coal and whale oil. So to focus only on
“sustainability” of resources commonly used today is to lose sight of
the fact that these resources likely have substitutes that will become
available if supplies of today's resources fall below critical levels.
No comments:
Post a Comment