How to Get It Wrong
Last week I participated in a conference organized by Rethinking Economics,
a student-run group hoping to promote, you guessed it, a rethinking of
economics. And Mammon knows that economics needs rethinking in the wake
of a disastrous crisis, a crisis that was neither predicted nor
prevented.
It
seems to me, however, that it’s important to realize that the enormous
intellectual failure of recent years took place at several levels.
Clearly, economics as a discipline went badly astray in the years —
actually decades — leading up to the crisis. But the failings of
economics were greatly aggravated by the sins of economists, who far too
often let partisanship or personal self-aggrandizement trump their
professionalism. Last but not least, economic policy makers
systematically chose to hear only what they wanted to hear. And it is
this multilevel failure — not the inadequacy of economics alone — that
accounts for the terrible performance of Western economies since 2008.
In
what sense did economics go astray? Hardly anyone predicted the 2008
crisis, but that in itself is arguably excusable in a complicated world.
More damning was the widespread conviction among economists that such a
crisis couldn’t happen.
Underlying this complacency was the dominance of an idealized vision of
capitalism, in which individuals are always rational and markets always
function perfectly.
Now,
idealized models have a useful role to play in economics (and indeed in
any discipline), as ways to clarify your thinking. But starting in the
1980s it became harder and harder to publish anything questioning these
idealized models in major journals. Economists trying to take account of
imperfect reality faced what Harvard’s Kenneth Rogoff, hardly a radical
figure (and someone I’ve sparred with) once called “new neoclassical repression.”
And it should go without saying that assuming away irrationality and
market failure meant assuming away the very possibility of the kind of
catastrophe that overtook the developed world six years ago.
Still,
many applied economists retained a more realistic vision of the world,
and textbook macroeconomics, while it didn’t predict the crisis, did a
pretty good job of predicting how things would play out in the
aftermath. Low interest rates in the face of big budget deficits, low
inflation in the face of a rapidly growing money supply, and sharp
economic contraction in countries imposing fiscal austerity came as
surprises to the talking heads on TV, but they were just what the basic
models predicted under the conditions that prevailed postcrisis.
But
while economic models didn’t perform all that badly after the crisis,
all too many influential economists did — refusing to acknowledge error,
letting naked partisanship trump analysis, or both. “Hey, I claimed
that another depression wasn’t possible, but I wasn’t wrong, it’s all
because businesses are reacting to the future failure of Obamacare.”
You
might say that this is just human nature, and it’s true that while the
most shocking intellectual malfeasance has come from conservative
economists, some economists on the left have also seemed more interested
in defending their turf and sniping at professional rivals than in
getting it right. Still, this bad behavior has come as a shock,
especially to those who thought we were having a real conversation.
If
you imagine that policy makers have spent the past five or six years in
thrall to economic orthodoxy, you’ve been misled. On the contrary, key
decision makers have been highly receptive to innovative, unorthodox
economic ideas — ideas that also happen to be wrong but which offered
excuses to do what these decision makers wanted to do anyway.
The great majority
of policy-oriented economists believe that increasing government
spending in a depressed economy creates jobs, and that slashing it
destroys jobs — but European leaders and U.S. Republicans decided to
believe the handful of economists
asserting the opposite. Neither theory nor history justifies panic over
current levels of government debt, but politicians decided to panic
anyway, citing unvetted (and, it turned out, flawed) research as justification.
I’m
not saying either that economics is in good shape or that its flaws
don’t matter. It isn’t, they do, and I’m all for rethinking and
reforming a field.
The
big problem with economic policy is not, however, that conventional
economics doesn’t tell us what to do. In fact, the world would be in
much better shape than it is if real-world policy had reflected the
lessons of Econ 101. If we’ve made a hash of things — and we have — the
fault lies not in our textbooks, but in ourselves.
No comments:
Post a Comment