‘Demokratie. Der Gott, Der Keiner Ist'
by Hans-Hermann Hoppe
by Hans-Hermann Hoppe
by Hans-Hermann Hoppe
It gives me great satisfaction and confidence to see my most recent book published in Germany.
That
is not quite as obvious as it may appear, for Germany is not a free
country. Not even freedom of speech exists in Germany. Here, whoever
publicly contradicts certain governmentally approved pronouncements will
be jailed, and whoever expresses "politically incorrect" ideas will be
neutralized and silenced.
In recent years, for the first time noticeable resistance against this saddening state of affairs has surfaced.1
"Politically
incorrect" is what the rulers and in particular the victors among the
rulers proclaim. The great victor of the 20th century, in particular as
far as Germany is concerned, is the USA. Hence, the USA has determined
the "correct" interpretation especially of recent history. Defeated
Germany was not only occupied, but also reeducated. Germany's schools
and universities, under almost complete government control, and the
governmentally licensed mass media, have proclaimed to this day the
official American view of history and in particular of the 20th century
as a triumph of good over evil.
Yet
after more than 50 years of occupation and reeducation, themes and
subjects are publicly discussed again in Germany, which do not easily
fit the American world view and hence were taboo for a long time (even
more so in defeated Germany than in the victorious USA): the
bloodthirsty beginning of the modern USA with the military conquest,
devastation, and lasting occupation of the secessionist South by the
Union government in the second American War of Independence), the
intentional entanglement of the USA in World War I, the fall of the
Czar, the German and Austrian Kaiser and the Versailles peace dictate,
the extent of the crimes of Lenin and Stalin and their role in the rise
of Mussolini and Hitler, the friendly association between Roosevelt and
Stalin and the decades-long communist takeover of all of Eastern and
Middle Europe that resulted from it, the Allied terror bombing of German
civilians and the American mistreatment of German prisoners of war, the
delivery of Western prisoners of war to Stalin for execution, and the
expulsion of millions of Germans.
My
investigations presented here are also "politically incorrect." Thus,
they fit into an intellectual landscape that is characterized by an
increasingly "revisionist" receptivity, and it can be hoped (at least I
hope so) that it may fall on fertile ground and have a liberating effect
especially in Germany.
Indeed,
my theses are more "incorrect" and my proposed revisions of the
orthodox view of history more fundamental and far-reaching than anything
heard on the subject heretofore. Notwithstanding my critical stance
vis-à-vis America, however, my work provides little consolation for
Germany and the Germans (is not the German political system merely a
copy of the American?).
The
central subject of the following studies is the modern American system
of a constitutional democratic state. Almost all Americans are convinced
of the superiority of their political system. The American
neo-conservatives, that group of formerly extreme left and now
social-democratic intellectuals who first came to fame and influence
during the Reagan administration and who presently exercise a dominating
influence on the Bush administration, go even further. They believe
that the constitutional democratic state, exemplified by the USA,
represents the highest, unsurpassable form of social organization. To
them, no social system is conceivable that is principally superior to a
constitutional democratic state. With the acceptance of the American
system, then, the "end of history" is reached, constitutionally and
ideologically. (It is no wonder that the neo-conservatives are always at
the forefront of American warmongers: democracy must be exported, if
need be by military might, into misbehaving, un-American regions. This
is what the Weltgeist demands.)
This
widely accepted thesis (especially also in Germany) is examined and
refuted in my studies. The full theoretical and historical case for my
contrary claim is to be found in my following investigations. Here, the
result can only be sketched, historically and in particular
theoretically truncated and abridged.
The
American model — democracy — must be regarded as a historical error,
economically as well as morally. Democracy promotes shortsightedness,
capital waste, irresponsibility, and moral relativism. It leads to
permanent compulsory income and wealth redistribution and legal
uncertainty. It is counterproductive. It promotes demagoguery and
egalitarianism. It is aggressive and potentially totalitarian
internally, vis-à-vis its own population, as well as externally. In sum,
it leads to a dramatic growth of state power, as manifested by the
amount of parasitically — by means of taxation and expropriation —
appropriated government income and wealth in relation to the amount of
productively — through market exchange — acquired private income and
wealth, and by the range and invasiveness of state legislation.
Democracy is doomed to collapse, just as Soviet communism was doomed to
collapse.
Classical
(pre-revolutionary) monarchy appears in a far more favorable light than
democracy. It is part of the dominant, American-influenced world view
that the process, beginning with the American and French revolution and
essentially concluding with the end of World War I, of the substitution
of presidents and prime ministers for kings represents historical
progress. The following investigations show that the opposite is the
case. The transition from a monarchical world to a democratic one must
be regarded as de-civilizing retrogression. In other words, we would be
better off today as far as living standards and liberty are concerned
than we actually are, if we had never adopted the American system.
Unlike
democratic "caretakers" of "public goods," kings, as proprietors of
these same goods, take a long-run view and are interested in the
preservation or enhancement of capital values. They are considered
personally responsible for their actions and bound by pre-existing laws.
They are not the makers of law; they apply old and eternal law.
Independent of popular elections, they have little need for demagoguery,
redistribution and egalitarianism (the lack of which is all good for
economic development). In sum, the monarchical state is comparatively
moderate and mild: with low tax revenue and little invasive and
oppressive.
Notwithstanding some clear sympathy for classical monarchy, I am not a monarchist, however.
Both classical monarchy and modern democracy are state
forms. That is, each claims for itself a monopoly of ultimate judgeship
and of taxation regarding the inhabitants of a given territory: I, and I
alone, that is their credo, am the final judge in cases of social
conflict, and I alone can appropriate the property of others' without
their consent. In light of this incentive structure, it is to be
expected of every statist social order that the price of law and order
always rises, while its quality falls. The higher the tax revenue and
the lower one's own productive efforts, the better off the state's
occupants are.
On the one hand, the existence of a state thus leads to the development and promotion of parasitism. As tax-receivers, it is possible for the occupants of the state to live without working, i.e., without having to give the tax-payers
something they consider worthwhile in return. Contrary to still
wide-spread Marxist mythology, it is not the entrepreneurs who exploit
their workers. Rather, it is the occupants of the state — the king and
his court in the case of monarchy; the president, the parliament, and
the so-called public service in the case of democracy, i.e., those who
most vocally claim to work for the public good — who actually live
exploitatively and parasitically at the expense of others. The higher
the state revenue, the better off the parasites are and/or the more
parasites there are.
Worse
still, as final judge in all matters of conflict, the occupants of the
state are in a position not only to arbitrate conflicts expensively and
miserably, but to actually cause and to provoke conflict in order
to then "solve" it to their own advantage. That is, a statist order not
only produces low quality goods at excessive prices and thus promotes
parasitism, but it produces evil and injustice, and it
promotes, especially under democratic conditions (when entry into the
state apparatus is open to everyone), the development of evil characters
and evil character traits.
My
historical revisionism goes further, then. Not only was the transition
from monarchy to democracy a historical error; the institution of the
modern, post-medieval state itself represents an error of great
consequence. However, contrary to neo-conservative assertions, a morally
as well as economically superior alternative to both democracy and
monarchy is always available: a natural order (a term consciously chosen
for its pre-monarchic medieval-scholastic connotations).
In
a natural order, all goods are the private property of some person or
group of persons. Streets, airports, waterways, all land and every
structure — everything is someone's private property. There exists no
state, no taxation, no judicial monopoly and no public property.
Security — property protection, law and order — like other goods and
services is provided by means of self-help, in neighborly cooperation,
and in association with freely financed specialized security firms.
Along with individual or neighborly efforts such as fences, walls, bars,
locks, warning devices, knives and revolvers, contractually agreed upon
security provisions of all kinds are offered by freely competing
(unregulated) property and life-insurers, who work in cooperation with
independent and mutually competing arbiters and judges and independent
or associated enforcement agencies and police forces. As a result (and
in complete contrast to the outcome under statist conditions), the price
of security falls, while its quality increases.
Several
chapters of the following investigations deal with the description, the
theoretical explanation, and the historic-sociological illustration of
the legal-institutional and economic workings of a natural order, with
its moral and economic advantages over a statist order, and with the
strategic means of achieving it under current conditions.
German
and American reviewers of the English original of this book have noted
that it is more, and wants to be more, than cool analysis and
explanation. It is written with a practical purpose. It is intended to
define, to motivate, and to shape a political movement. It wants to mold
classical (old) conservatives and libertarian free market advocates
ideologically together in a unified bourgeois fundamental opposition to
the democratic central state and its inherent parasitism and injustice
(and even more so against a super- or world-state), and to generate
excitement for the old idea of a natural order and (as a means to this
end) of secession.
The
USA has always had a fundamental anti-statist opposition (and it is
this fact alone, and the moderating or rather radicalizing intellectual
influence of this opposition on American public opinion which lets
America to this day stay ahead of European countries and in particular
Germany). However, this opposition was faced with steady statist
temptations and threats, and confronted with the Soviet Union and the
Cold War it was increasingly confused, splintered and decimated.
At
the end of the 1980s, to counteract this decline and to again lend
expression to a fundamental conservative-libertarian opposition,
intellectuals associated with the Ludwig von Mises Institute, the Center for Libertarian Studies, and the political-cultural monthly Chronicles
met during several years for regular open private conferences. The
moment was favorable. The communist Soviet Empire had collapsed at the
end of the 1980s; and as a consequence, the ideological receptivity of
the public had risen and was higher than it had been in decades.
Initiator and spiritus rector
of this intellectual endeavor until his death in 1995 was Murray N.
Rothbard, the outstanding American student of the Austrian economist and
social theorist Ludwig von Mises and the founder of the American
libertarian movement. Next to Rothbard, it was in particular Llewellyn
H. Rockwell Jr., founder and president of the Ludwig von Mises Institute, Thomas Fleming, Chronicles
editor, the intellectual historian and political philosopher Paul
Gottfried, the historians Clyde Wilson and Ralph Raico, the writers and
columnists Samuel Francis and Joseph Sobran, and the author of these
lines, who made fundamental and programmatic contributions at these
occasions. Self-ironically one referred to oneself as the Paleos, and
under this name one was quickly also officially registered (and
infamously-famous).
Meanwhile,
facilitated by the Internet, the Paleos have become a flourishing and
rapidly growing intellectual movement. The first and foremost Paleo
address, LewRockwell.com,
with daily changing political, economic, and cultural analysis and
commentary, ranks among the most widely read websites of its kind. It
has more daily readers than the websites of the White House, the Washington Times, the National Review, the Weekly Standard, Forbes, the Economist, the Spiegel, the FAZ, the Sueddeutsche Zeitung, the Handelsblatt, and the Bildzeitung (and nearly as many as the Wall Street Journal).
This
book, now in its fifth printing, is my personal, specifically
theoretical and European contribution to the construction of an
ideological identity for this conservative-libertarian Paleo-movement.
Today,
in Germany no fundamentally anti-statist bourgeois opposition exists.
In many circles, Germany and anti-statism are simply considered
antonyms. As the American historian Raico has shown, however, until the
beginning of the 20th century such an opposition did exist in Germany.2
Its disappearance is another sorry result of democracy. With my
intellectual dismantling of democracy I hark back to this radical
liberal German tradition and hope to contribute to its revival. Germany
truly needs such a revival; and as someone who has always acknowledged
his German roots with self-assuredness and who never surrendered his
status as German citizen, I permit myself to say that Germany is also
truly deserving of such a rebirth.
No comments:
Post a Comment