Has the United States, by Virtue of Its Size and Complexity, Become Ungovernable?—
Richard Posner
There are, especially in Europe and
East Asia, and to a limited extent in the Western Hemisphere, small
countries that are well governed. But among large, populous countries,
there appears to be only one well-governed country: Germany. The United
States is the third largest country by land mass (after Russia and
Canada) and population (after India and China), the wealthiest, the
militarily most powerful, and generally regarded as the leading nation
in the world—its geopolitical center. But all these are negatives from
the standpoint of governance, as are the nation’s ethnic and cultural
diversity, political divisiveness, high crime rates, and highly unequal
distribution of income. Another major negative is the difficulty of
changing the U.S. Constitution. Although there have been a number of
amendments, the basic structure, set by the original Constitution of
1789, has not been changed significantly.
A serious problem of governance, or
management, that all but the smallest organizations, whether private or
governmental, encounter is the tension between the goals of the
organization and the personal goals, which typically differ, of the
individuals who comprise the organization. Stated differently, the
individuals have personal utility functions that differ from the
organization’s utility function. The larger the organization, the
greater the divergence is likely to be and the more difficult to
minimize. The organization that is the federal government of the United
States has more than 4 million employees.
Competition between organizations is an
important control on the divergence (which economists refer to as
“agency costs”—the costs created by the fact that the employees of an
organization have their own goals that often conflict with those of
their employer). But nations do not feel the same competitive pressures
as corporations. Even a small, miserable, effectively bankrupt nation
like Greece does not disappear, as large corporations not infrequently
do, because of its inefficiency. Because corporations are simpler and
smaller and also more constrained by competition than nations, we can
expect them to be managed more efficiently, and specifically to adopt an
organizational structure that minimizes agency costs. So let’s glance
at the structure of the typical large corporation and compare it to our
federal government structure. There will be a board of directors to
exercise a general but loose supervision over the corporation (and in
turn subject to very loose control by the shareholders), intervening
decisively only in crisis situations or where there is vacancy in the
office of the Chief Executive Officer. The CEO will be the dominant
figure in the corporation, exercising something close to dictatorial
power, assisted by a small personal staff. Often he will overshadow the
chairman of the board of directors—he may even double as chairman and
CEO. There will be a Chief Operating Officer, exercising day to day
management, while the CEO, as the public face of the corporation, will
formulate policy, provide overall guidance, inspiration, and “vision,”
appoint the major subordinate corporate officials (general counsel,
chief information officer, chief financial officer, etc.), and maintain
personal relations with important investors, customers, competitors, and
regulatory officials. The corporation will have several or many
operating divisions, reporting to the COO or CEO, each headed by a vice
president or equivalent. The employees in each division will serve at
the pleasure of their superiors; no one will have fixed tenure.
Compare the federal government. The
closest to a board of directors is the Congress, but it differs mainly
in having a good deal of policy responsibility, and, since it does not
appoint and is not appointed by the President (corresponding to a
corporate CEO), there is no presumption that its policy preferences will
coincide with the President’s. The President’s exercise of his own
policymaking powers will often work at cross-purposes with Congress’s
exercise of its powers; nor can he appoint senior officials without the
concurrence of a division of the Congress, namely the Senate. A further
dilution of presidential power results form the existence of an
independent federal judiciary, headed by the Supreme Court. Federal
judges and Justices have lifetime tenure, can invalidate legislative and
executive action both federal and state, and rarely (because of that
tenure) will a President be able to appoint a majority of the Supreme
Court Justices or other federal judges.
The President has a personal staff
(officially the “Executive Office of the President”) that numbers more
than 2000. The staff assists him in overseeing the large number of
“divisions” (executive departments, such as State and Defense and
free-standing agencies such as the Environmental Protection Agency) into
which the federal government is divided. The heads of these divisions,
however, do not have hiring or firing authority, as a practical matter,
over most of the employees, who are tenured civil servants. The heads
serve short terms, and often are appointed for political reasons
unrelated to experience or competence. The brevity of their terms and
frequent lack of relevant skills or knowledge create tense relations
with the tenured bureaucrats. As a result, the President’s control over
the more than 4 million federal employees (of whom about 40 percent are
military) is as a practical matter quite limited.
A further division of government is
brought about by federalism: the division of the nation into 50 states,
each with quasi-sovereign powers. The federal government has
considerable power over the states, but far less than a CEO or COO would
have over the operating divisions of their corporation.
The structure of the federal government
reflects the state of the nation in the eighteenth century. The
population was roughly 1 percent of what it is today, there were only 13
states and as a result the Congress was small, and the federal
government was tiny. It is doubtful that starting over in today’s
circumstances a constitutional convention would create a similar
system.
The most glaring deficiency is the
limited authority of the President and the absence of an official
corresponding to the Chief Operating Officer of a private corporation.
From an efficiency standpoint the President should be able to promulgate
laws (not just regulations), subject to override by supermajorities of
Congress; appoint subordinate officials without the concurrence of the
Senate; and create a position analogous to that of a COO; this would
result in a structure analogous to that of France, which has both a
President and a prime minister, the latter being in charge of day to day
governmental operations (though France is not an example of a
well-governed country). The President should also be authorized to
control the finances of the states, alter their boundaries, appoint
their principal officials, and veto their laws. And no civil servants
should have tenure. The result of all these changes would be to conform
American government to the “government” of a large private corporation.
Maybe the President would become the
“outside” partner and his Chief Operating Officer the “inside” partner,
the former dealing with relations with foreign countries (in the
broadest sense, comprehending not only foreign relations in the
conventional sense, but also immigration, trade, and military assistance
and intervention), the latter with the formulation and implementation
of domestic policies.
Of course these are not feasible
reforms. Anything that strengthens the President weakens other sources
of power, not only in the government itself (legislators, civil
servants) but also in the private sector, which through campaign
donations and other forms of political activity exert a powerful and
self-interested influence on governmental action, resulting in enormous
waste and perversity.
In an interesting and ominous book by Joseph A. Tainter called The Collapse of Complex Societies
(1988), the author points to historical episodes of collapse of
societies that had become too complex to manage effectively, such as the
Mayan civilization of Central American and the Western Roman Empire.
Successful societies, such as Britain, the United States, and Germany,
in the nineteenth century, and Japan and the Soviet Union in roughly the
first half of the twentieth century, tend, like successful companies,
to expand. Expansion makes governance more complex, which can lead to
ungovernability and eventual collapse. Companies that become
ungovernable can shrink to a manageable size by selling off parts of
themselves; or they can simply liquidate, in which event their assets
are sold to other companies. There are examples in the government
sphere, as in the peaceful division of Czechoslovakia into Slovakia and
the Czech Republic, or the peaceful dissolution of the Soviet Union, but
more often such fragmentation is involuntary, often indeed violent.
No comments:
Post a Comment